A quantitative model of technological catch-up

  • Authors

    • Hossein Gholizadeh
    • Ali Bonyadi Naeini Assistant Professor, Department of Progress Engineering, Iran University of Science and Technology
    • Alireza Moini Assistant Professor, Department of Progress Engineering, Iran University of Science and Technology
    2015-02-24
    https://doi.org/10.14419/ijet.v4i1.4203
  • Technological Leapfrogging, Technological Gap, Path Dependency, Windows of Opportunity, Metafrontier, Stochastic Frontier.
  • Abstract

    This article presents a quantitative model for the analysis of technological gap. The rates of development of technological leaders and followers in nanotechnology are expressed in terms of coupled equations. On the basis of this model (first step) comparative technological gap and rate of that will be studied. We can calculate the dynamics of the gap between leader and follower. In the Second step, we estimate the technology gap using the metafrontier approach. Then we test the relationship between the technology gap and the quality of dimensions of the Catch-up technology which were identified in previous step. The usefulness of this approach is then demonstrated in the analysis of the technological gap of nanotechnology in Iran, the leader in Middle East and the world. We shall present the behaviors of the technological leader and followers. At the end, analyzing Iran position will be identified and implying effective dimension of catch-up Suggestions will be offered which could be a fundamental for long-term policies of Iran.

  • References

    1. [1] Lall, S. and C. Pietrobelli, National technology systems in sub-Saharan Africa. International Journal of Technology and Globalisation, 2005. 1(3): p. 311-342. http://dx.doi.org/10.1504/IJTG.2005.008746.

      [2] Burkett, P. and M. Hart-Landsberg, A critique of “catch-up†theories of development. Journal of Contemporary Asia, 2003. 33(2): p. 147-171. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00472330380000101.

      [3] Chesbrough, H.W., Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from technology2003: Harvard Business Press.

      [4] Radosevic, S., International technology transfer and catch-up in economic development. 1999.

      [5] Grossman, G.M. and E.L.-C. Lai, International protection of intellectual property: Corrigendum. American Economic Review, 2006. 96(1): p. 456. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/000282806776157506.

      [6] Vedeler, C., Productivity Growth in South Africa and the Effects of Foreign Direct Investments: A time series analysis. 2013.

      [7] Falvey, R., N. Foster, and D. Greenaway, Imports, exports, knowledge spillovers and growth. Economics Letters, 2004. 85(2): p. 209-213. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2004.04.007.

      [8] Patel, P. and K. Pavitt, National innovation systems: why they are important, and how they might be measured and compared. Economics of innovation and new technology, 1994. 3(1): p. 77-95. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10438599400000004.

      [9] Acemoglu, D. and J.A. Robinson, Political losers as a barrier to economic development. The American Economic Review, 2000. 90(2): p. 126-130. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.2.126.

      [10] Mu, Q. and K. Lee, Knowledge diffusion, market segmentation and technological catch-up: The case of the telecommunication industry in China. Research Policy, 2005. 34(6): p. 759-783. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2005.02.007.

      [11] Abramovitz, M., Thinking about growth: And other essays on economic growth and welfare1989: Cambridge University Press. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511664656.

      [12] Silverberg, G. and B. Verspagen, Learning, innovation and economic growth: a long-run model of industrial dynamics. Industrial and Corporate Change, 1994. 3(1): p. 199-223. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/icc/3.1.199.

      [13] Lundvall, B.-Ä. and B. Johnson, The learning economy. Journal of industry studies, 1994. 1(2): p. 23-42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13662719400000002.

      [14] Mazzoleni, R. and R.R. Nelson, Public research institutions and economic catch-up. Research Policy, 2007. 36(10): p. 1512-1528. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2007.06.007.

      [15] Manca, F., Technology catch-up and the role of institutions. Journal of macroeconomics, 2010. 32(4): p. 1041-1053. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2010.07.004.

      [16] Póvoa, L.M.C. and M.S. Rapini, Technology transfer from universities and public research institutes to firms in Brazil: what is transferred and how the transfer is carried out. Science and Public Policy, 2010. 37(2): p. 147-159. http://dx.doi.org/10.3152/030234210X496619.

      [17] Nelson, R.R. and E.S. Phelps, Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. The American Economic Review, 1966. 56(1/2): p. 69-75.

      [18] Dollar, D. and A. Kraay, Institutions, trade, and growth. Journal of monetary economics, 2003. 50(1): p. 133-162. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00206-4.

      [19] Battese, G.E., D.P. Rao, and C.J. O'Donnell, A metafrontier production function for estimation of technical efficiencies and technology gaps for firms operating under different technologies. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 2004. 21(1): p. 91-103. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/B:PROD.0000012454.06094.29.

  • Downloads

  • How to Cite

    Gholizadeh, H., Bonyadi Naeini, A., & Moini, A. (2015). A quantitative model of technological catch-up. International Journal of Engineering & Technology, 4(1), 233-243. https://doi.org/10.14419/ijet.v4i1.4203

    Received date: 2015-01-18

    Accepted date: 2015-02-10

    Published date: 2015-02-24